‘Failed states’ and ‘state failure’ have emerged as the dominant themes of discourse and analysis in the post-Cold War period. Ever since the first time usage by Helman and Ratner almost two decades ago, these concepts have inspired conceptual insights from scholars, policy makers and practitioners. Such insights not only attempt at defining the concept of ‘state failure,’ but also focus upon developing indices and indexes for measuring state failure across a broad spectrum of socio-political and economic indicators. This paper argues that the state failure indices, which measure political, economic and social indicators for predicting state’s present status and future risks of failure, reveal a strong pro-Weberian bias. The indices place emphasis on failed states being characterized by lack of monopoly over force, service provision and democratic legitimacy. This is notwithstanding the fact that all these concepts are highly debated and contested. It further criticizes the state failure indices for using dissimilar indicators to predict instability and, therefore, producing indices that are reasonably at variance with each other. It also raises objections on these indices being based on empirical data and therefore, ignoring the socio-political undercurrents in a state, which may burst out and result in complete regime displacements. Therefore, none of the indices could predict authoritarian Arab regimes being challenged by popular discontent and falling like house of cards.
Key words: State failure, failure and fragility indices, Weberian and Western state, socio-political and economic indicators.
The state as defined and understood today is a more recent European phenomenon. But, taken as a politically organized community, it has over the centuries existed as a physical reality and construed as an abstract idea. In pre-modern political theory, the state and society were indistinguishable; the Greeks conceived of it as an all inclusive, natural and necessary institution from which an individual derived the meaning of his existence. Plato emphasized the state’s origin from individual’s lack of self sufficiency, which forced him to live in a society; ‘it (the state) springs…from our needs,’ he declared. The state’s naturalness, to Aristotle, stems from its emergence out of other natural associations, including families, households and villages. And since the state to him embodies a whole, it has a clear priority over its parts and therefore, superiority over other earlier forms of associations. It was on the ashes of the Greek City States that the Great Roman Empire arose, whose contribution to the rise of modern statehood was state’s peculiarity from the individuals it represented. The conflation of state and society in Greek political thought was replaced by Roman theory’s distinction of an individual from the state. Rome granted citizenship rights to its citizens and governed them under a systemized code-the Roman Law. The decline of the Roman Empire led to a period of decentralized governance system under feudalism in Medieval Europe. Modern state system grew out of the contradictions of feudalism and the need for a single sovereign to assert his authority over rival lords, the Church and other contenders to his sovereignty.
Modern state system’s rise at the end of medieval period in Europe stimulated political theorizing on the nature and function of the state. It was seen as a relationship of contract between the rulers and the ruled by the contract thinkers. While Hobbes, surrendered individual’s freedom to an absolute sovereign in return for guarantees of peace and security, Locke, conditioned the exercise of sovereign powers by the ruler on popular consent. And Rousseau, explored general will or a shared understanding of common good and well being as the basis of contract between the ruler and ruled and therefore, contended that citizens under such a contract remained free in fulfilling legal obligations and obeying state laws. The state’s perception as a contractual binding between the ruler and the individuals is reflected in definitions of the state as a set of social relations between the political authority/government and the society, which underlines citizen’s acknowledgement of state’s regulatory authority in return for provisions of security and social justice (Lockean tradition). This is the functionalist approach to defining a state.
The nature and character of the state was further theorized by the Marxists, who saw the state as a manifestation of class struggle between the pre-state kinship based social order characterized by low development of wealth and labour, with the new classes that resulted from a progression of growth in productivity of labour, private property and exchange. In the class struggle that is a product of differences of wealth and control over the utilization of the labour powers of others, old kinship based society withers away giving way to the emergence of a new one based on control over the state. This materialistic explanation for state emergence through a class struggle is forwarded by the Marxists as the basis for the origin of the state throughout written history. The state is perceived as a tool of exploitation used for perpetuation of dominant ruling class’s power. And therefore, the revolution by proletariat is supposed to do away with the state and create a basis for a classless, stateless society.
The understanding of the state corresponding to its modern image as the holder of monopoly over force, developed with the rise of the European state system from 15th Century onwards. The state as the ultimate holder of monopoly over force and violence was defined in the early 20th Century by the German sociologist Max Weber. He chose to emphasize the means peculiar to the state-physical force (organizational and structural aspects), rather than the ends and defined it as ‘a human community that successfully claims the monopoly of legitimate use of physical force within a given territory.’ This emphasis on monopoly of violence over a territorially bounded population reflecting the empirical dimension of the state is largely the criteria used for defining a modern state. Laski, for example argues that the state’s binding characteristic of commanding obedience legally and power to enforce its laws on all in its territory gives it primacy over other forms of social groupings. The Weberian definition reflects an institutionalist approach of defining a state, wherein, the institutions of army, police, bureaucracy and judiciary extend state’s monopoly of force and order within its territorial boundaries.
Modern state is further credited with possessing the juridical or external dimension of conducting autonomous relations with other sovereign entities in the international state system. Juridical sovereignty is a function of possessing a territorial boundary recognized by international law, obtained by states, either by declaration, or recognition by other states, which confers on it the right of statehood, even in the absence of empirical attributes. The juridical and empirical dimensions of statehood are combined by international law to define a state to possess a permanent population, a defined territory, a government and a capacity to enter into relations with other states. Since states are the principal subjects of international law, therefore, a state’s recognized capacity to maintain external relations with other states is the most important qualification as far as international law is concerned. The modern state is therefore, understood to have a recognized territory, a population that sees itself as belonging to the state and a government that has a monopoly of legitimate force within its territory and the capacity to enter into formal relations with other entities.
European colonialism diffused modern statehood to other parts of the world but state growth did not follow its Western counterpart experience. Independence, conferred statehood on non-Western states irrespective of the growth of empirical characteristics associated with institutional and functional understanding of the state. To borrow Jackson and Rosberg’s words, empirical attributes of statehood in the form of a stable population and effective government are seriously contested and challenged in these countries. This did not prevent extension of a Weberian concept to define statehood in non-Western societies. Loose state control over territory, patrimonial governance, low service delivery capacity, lesser popular political participation and economic backwardness characterize these states. The prevalence of weak statehood does not affect juridical or external dimension of states because it is not synonym with the loss of sovereignty under international concepts of sovereignty. It is also not a criterion for state’s recognition under international law, or its admission, or withdrawal from the international state system, because otherwise, it would collide with the UN principle of self determination of states.
The above section argued that the concept of state is heavily Western inspired. Its functional meaning originated from the writings of social contract theorists who saw the state as a form of contractual relationship in which the monarch was bound to perform certain duties and the population was in turn meant to obey him. The institutional dimension of monopoly over the legitimate use of force came up as European rulers embarked on a process of state making in Europe. Among the current manifestations, state’s juridical aspect of ability to engage in relationship with other states is significant. But, the extension of state system to non-Western societies created very weak replicas of Western counterpart, who were born with many feeble features of empirical statehood. And that is why a purely Weberian definition and understanding was never a reflection of the state in the non-Western societies.
This section argues that the indices and indexes that predict future risk of state failure and rank states in accordance with their level of performance signify a pro-Weberian bias. The benchmarks for political, economic and social indicators for state performance are set against those present in developed countries. Most indices with the exception of ‘Mo Ibrahim Index of African Governance,’ provide rankings across the developing world. The State Failure Task Force (now Political Instability Task Force-PITF), is US government funded (1994) earliest attempt at predicting onset of instability in different regions of the world over a 50 year period. Defining state failure as a severe political crisis on account of revolutionary and ethnic wars, adverse regime change from authoritarianism to democracy and genocides/politicides, the Task Force developed a Global Model for Forecasting Political Instability. The findings of the Task Force Reports suggest regime type as the most frequent type of state failure; Phase III Report (1955-2000) found partial democracies at seven times higher risk of failure than full democracies and autocracies. Phase V (1955-2003) Report found one third of all instability onset occurring in partial democracies that were characterized by factionalism. It also identifies state led discrimination, ethnic diversity, regime type, neighbourhood effects, recent ethnic war or genocide and youth bulge to be significant risk factors for the onset of ethnic wars and state failure.
Other than the PITF, most indexes of state failure provide rankings for potential failures. The following table provides information on these indexes, briefly describing the methodology, major findings and their rankings of top 10 failed states. The end of the table is followed by a critical appreciation of these indexes and indices.
Table – 2: State Failure/ Fragility Indexes
The state fragility indices delve comprehensively into the question of how to explain state failure, by applying largely a Western and Weberian lens. Inability of a state to deliver core functions in security, service provision, political and economic management and abiding by international transactions are recurrent themes in different indices. Whereas, lack of popular legitimacy constitutes a part of three indices, economic underdevelopment is taken up as a major determinant of weakness by Brookings Index of State Weakness, which strongly emphasizes its co-relation with ‘critical state weakness’ or failure. The rest of the indices either specifically evade economic underperformance as a prominent feature of failure or grant it a lower place below security, order, service provision and legitimacy. CIDCM Peace and Conflict Instability Ledger, adopts the State Failure Task Force Report’s state failure definition of authority deficiency on account of onset of revolutionary, ethnicity, regime change and genocides/politicides related wars in states. The equation of state failure with onset of wars is problematic and fails to account for relatively stable authority structures in some states long beset by civil war conditions. Sri Lanka is one example, where a civil war of 25 years failed to damage the authority and capacity of the central government. It is an exception, but demonstrates that in some cases, civil war and violence may not precipitate breakdown of authority or affect the legitimacy of the regime in power.
The state failure indices by measuring political, economic and social indicators for predicting a state’s present status and its future risks of failure reveal a strong pro-Weberian bias. Most indices explain the phenomenon of state failure in contrast to Weber’s dictum of an institutional, functional and legitimate state. The emphasis on non-provision of security as synonymous with the loss of monopoly over force is a highly debatable and contested concept. It is because monopoly over violence in a defined territory or state is not even the prerogative of the First World, let alone the Third World. Monopoly over violence in the developed world stands challenged by two processes: outsourcing of military tasks to private arms companies; and supra-national control by the UN over deployment decisions of the armed and security forces of these developed states, especially in post intervention conflict regions. This situation is starker for the new members of the international state system who compromise their sovereignty to the forces of globalization in different respects. State’s sovereignty is being shared at a supra-national level with multinational companies and NGOs and at a bottom-up level with sub-national local governments. In the developing world, various actors and structures (including violent manifestations), such as militant commanders and warlords, paramilitary group and criminal gangs, work to decentralize state’s control over violence and security. In some weak and fragile states, they even maintain social orders and perform governance functions. Instead of monopoly over violence, such a scenario is manifested by ‘oligopoly of violence’. The phenomenon of monopoly is also challenged by wars and conflict in neighbouring states, which create conditions for loosening of state’s monopoly over violence too, especially in situations when borders are defined by homogenous populations on both sides.
The state’s exercise of monopoly over violence in the Third World is not only challenged internally by sub-state informal and traditional actors and structures, but also by supra-state International Governmental Organizations (INGOs) and regional organizations that often exercise control over the decisions of where the armed forces of a particular state needed to be deployed for peace keeping and peace building. Globalization and its concomitant effects have increased security predicaments for the developing world by making states address a broad range of environmental, economic, socio-political and security concerns that are largely beyond the control and capacity of their governments. Historically too, several processes in the Third World, have prevented them from achieving this monopoly and it is unrealistic to expect them to deliver on this function in a short period of time, when the Western World took a much longer time to realize the same. The so called ‘Third World’ has been independent for only a few decades and therefore, Milliken and Krause stress that while Europe took hundreds of years to provide security and services to its citizens, it is unrealistic to expect the developing world to acquire it in a short time horizon. In a similar vein, Bilgin and Morton, are highly critical of using Western criteria of statehood to define failed states and call it ‘deception of sovereignty’, which result from comparing a Western institutional transplant possessing conditions and processes that developed over a much longer period. By emphasizing monopoly over violence, these explanations fail to appreciate the different international environment of state formation in the Western and non-Western societies and First World’s role in conflict perpetuation in the Third World. That is why, Lambach, accuses scholars of ethno-centricism, on their attempts to apply Weberian ideal norms to inapplicable empirical situations in non-Western societies.
The emphasis in state failure indices on state’s monopoly over service provision is also a contested issue. Such explanations, not only fail to account for the useful contribution to service provision of indigenous, traditional, kinship and religious institutions, but also paint a wrongful picture of failed states, where absence of formal service provision is supposedly commensurate to total chaos and disorder. Such a picture is hardly true; even in cases of protracted war and violence informal institutions have managed to provide some form of social and political order. Understanding failed states from a liberal legitimacy deficit is further contested. Though, weak and fragile states may be lacking in Western democratic legitimacy features, however, their governance institutions are supported by other forms of traditional, populist or ideological legitimacy.
As for the use of indicators to predict fragility, all the indexes use a combination of political, social and economic indicators, with differences in the use of sub indicators. The use of differing sub-indicators provides different rankings for states as well as their failure predictions. The differences are especially stark when ranking regimes that are designated as authoritarian and autocratic. The indices that define state failure to embody loss of regime legitimacy, accord states which are deficient in democratic legitimacy, a descending position in order of merit, despite their relatively stable structures of authority. It is because regime legitimacy is measured through sub-indicators of popular political participation, civil society growth, media independence, regular and periodic elections and guarantee of fundamental rights, including women and minority rights. Other indices accord a first place to states deficient in authority and capacity, or economic growth, rather than democratic legitimacy and, therefore produce results that are conflicting with each other. Over all, the various indices provide more weightage to coercive apparatus strength and development of legal and juridical structures for predicting stability and failures.
The use of dissimilar indicators for measuring state effectiveness in service delivery, monopoly over violence, territorial control, legitimacy and economic development makes the concept of state failure difficult to quantify. For example, the economic position of a state may be aggregated by using statistics on GDP, GNP, per capita, openness to international trade, balance of payments and others, therefore, each list producing a different set of economically fragile states. Ziaja and Mata, criticize the fragility indices on using simple, additive aggregation methods for risk estimates and argue that since security is the most essential condition for stabilizing states, indices should not allow other dimensions such as economic or social to compensate for insecurity. They also argue that the thresholds for determining categorization of states are not theoretically or empirically justified, but are mostly simple fractions used by the index on a 0-10 scale. ‘These could be either theorized e.g. which fraction of its terrain must a state control to plausibly claim the monopoly of legitimate violence? Or empirically verified e.g. at which level of income has civil war never occurred?’ The aggregate sources may poorly reflect how states are actually performing across varied functions. Brinkerhoff, points to another weakness in these indices. He argues that the indices by using combinations of socio-political and economic indicators to predict failures, neglect root causes that failed the state in the first place and fail to highlight solutions for addressing fragility, including international intervention for rebuilding such states. The fragility indices also suffer from problems of finding reliable data to base their indicators on. Online government websites in developing states are usually relied upon to determine socio-economic and political data, however, these may suffer from reliability problems. Reliability issues arise on account of tendency to play around with such figures for reflecting a government’s stand point or because of data collection problems that stem from weak administrative capacity for conducting surveys and other techniques.
The rankings place Afghanistan among the list of the top failed, most fragile or critically weak states. Afghanistan’s relative position in CIDCM Peace and Conflict Instability Ledger 2012 is at the top in terms of estimated risk levels in all governance indicators, whereas, in other indexes, it stands among the top 5 most fragile states. The countries ahead of Afghanistan in terms of risk assessment are all African and mostly Muslim (Somalia and Sudan). In most indices, Afghanistan’s position has remained stagnant, but in CIFP State Fragility Index 2011, it went up from 3rd position (in previous indices) to being the 2nd most fragile state in the world. This reflects a highly volatile state building process, which despite the passage of more than a decade of state building and the presence of large numbers of external security forces has largely failed to give a stable policy to Afghanistan. Worrying trends of insecurity, lack of authority, low state capacity, rising militancy, violence, unstable economy and declining legitimacy, characterize in varying degrees the post 2001 state building process in the country.
The main findings of the reports attached to these indices, reflect interesting conclusions on the rankings as well as the estimated risk of failure and instability for future states. An interesting finding is that entrenched autocracies are less vulnerable to instability than partial democracies (anocracies) and in some instances, full democracies. Such a prediction is in itself challenged by the US invasion of Iraq, which not only dislodged the autocratic regime of Saddam Hussain, but also ushered in a period of extreme instability for the state. Therefore, these indices fail to provide external invasion as a factor for adverse regime change and instability while predicting risks of state failure. Similarly, internal pressures for popular participation and accountability that led to the breakdown of some Arab regimes (termed in literature as Arab uprising or Arab spring) is also unaccounted for in these indices. In the light of findings of these indices, the autocratic regimes were strong and maintained a semblance of order associated with state strength and stability. The experience of Arab spring shows that quantitative measurement of monopoly over force and order may conceal the qualitative underpinnings of the system in terms of popular dissatisfaction with regime performance, and popular notions of greater participation and accountability of such regimes.
With the exception of Index of State Weakness in the Developing World, the rest including, PITF, CSP State Fragility Index and Matrix, CIDCM Peace and Conflict Instability Ledger, and CIFP State Fragility Index, find partial democracies at greater risk of failure than autocracies or full democracies. Transition to full democracy fails, PITF, argues when electoral competition is introduced sans checks on the powers of the executive and a system of civil rights properly in place, as in an institutionalized political competition. CIDCM Peace and Conflict Instability Ledger, found partial democratic societies at a greater risk of failure owing to an inability to provide for group grievances and their tendency to contain dissension through repression. Some conclusions may be drawn here. First, increase in the number of democracies in post Cold War period has made the world more unstable- the odds for such partial democracies failing and destabilizing have increased substantially. Second, conventional state building emphasis on liberal democracy and electoral competition may not herald greater stability or peace in post conflict societies. Evidence in many peace building missions in 1990s substantiates the argument, as armed conflict and violence has immediately followed the withdrawal of foreign forces. Therefore, state building approach must look beyond simple introduction of democratic governance institutions in such conflict settings, where governance practices largely draw legitimacy form indigenous structures and institutions, such as Afghanistan. Third, coercive apparatus growth under prolong autocratic regimes is not reflective of stable statehood, unless, it serves to provide an outlet for accommodation of common grievances and expectations. And fourth, a significant youth bulge, especially in Muslim states may serve to indicate growth in levels of radical or revolutionary movements, resulting in adverse regime displacements, as lessons from Arab Spring suggest.
A few words on the merit of constructing indexes for measuring state fragility and failure. These indices are sponsored by institutions that are based primarily in the First World- mostly universities, private think tanks or in case of the PITF reports, the US government. The arguments in defense may be that since these indices measure state’s performance in relation to its past and present, as well as relative to that of the more successful states, therefore, changes in country performance in crucial sectors may be monitored and risk factors determined beforehand. The timely evaluation of risk assessment may help the international community in adopting preemptive steps for responding to crisis situations. In other words, the global instability forecasting models are valuable tools for making appropriate policies underlining state building intervention. These indices may help when international community finds it harder to interact with reliable local partners for aid prioritization in failed settings. They may also be helpful in determining which sectors need precedence over others, in terms of planning and financing development. In addition to prioritization of funding for needed sectors and fields, these indices may help donors to re-evaluate and reappraise the impact of aid policies and conditionalities on a timely basis.
The above section argued that institutionalist, functionalist and liberal approach of understanding a state has inspired qualitative and quantitative studies that measure state’s effectiveness and capacity across a broad range of service provision. These than either rank the states accordingly, or predict their future risk of instability and failure. This section contends that besides reflecting a Western account of state failure, these indices while noting state weaknesses and ranking them on a broad range of state functionality, fail to account for the relative differences in the strength of state institutions and variations in stability across autocratic and democratic regimes. It also criticizes such Indices for using differential or dissimilar indicators for measuring state strength and predicting failure, and therefore producing differing results in rankings and predictions across it. The merit of such indices stands in helping to guide donor agencies and policy makers in prioritizing funding by basing it on institutional performances across a broad range of state functions.
The humanitarian and security dilemmas connected to state failure and growing international intervention to arrest such failure, has stimulated researchers and scholars interest in defining and understanding the concept of failed states, developing indices for measuring state failure and predicting crisis of political instability for them. The state fragility indices predict state weakness and failure on the basis of defining a state purely on Weberian and Western statehood terms. Such a Weberian influence conceals the growth of non-Western states on a path that was very dissimilar to its Western counter-part. By stressing a total monopoly over force inside a state’s territorial boundary, these indices fail to appreciate that the modern state is challenged by a variety of supra-national global and sub-national local forces, actors and structures.
This paper explored the various state failure indices and indexes and criticized them for using dissimilar indicators to predict instability and, therefore, producing results that are reasonably at variance with each other. It also raises objections on these indices being based on empirical and quantitative data and therefore, ignoring the qualitative socio-political undercurrents in a state, which may lead to sudden and violent regime displacements. The result is that none of the indices could predict authoritarian Arab regimes being challenged by popular discontent and had instead predicted stability for these. The indices gave high scores of stability and authority to autocratic regimes and could not foresee the rise and spread of the Arab spring/revolt.
In constructing the merit for such state failure indexes, it is argued that these contribute to our understanding of the risks of failure on the basis of detailed analysis of socio-economic and political indicators. This may help in guiding international agencies and donor governments in timely and pre-emptive intervention for restoring authority and order in such states. But it is a just a theory bound assumption. The fact of the matter is that powerful states intervene in response to national and security interests and, not according to the merit of a particular case.
Anderson, Lisa. [Fall 2004]: Antiquated Before They Can Ossify: States that Fail Before They Form. In Journal of International Affairs,58 (1).
Aristotle. [1962]: The Politics, translated with an introduction by T.A. Sinclair. Middlesex: Penguin Books.
Axtmann, Roland. [July 2004]: The State of the State: The Model of the Modern State and its Contemporary Transformation. International Political Science Review, 25 (3).
Barker, Earnest. [1918]: Greek Political Theory: Plato and his Predecessors. Great Britain: Mathuen & Co Ltd.
Bilgin, Pinar. and Morton, Adam David. [2002]: Historicising Representations of Failed States: Beyond the Cold-War Annexation of the Social Sciences? In Third World Quarterly, 23 (1).
Bilgin, Pinar. and Morton, Adam David. [2007]: Rethinking State Failure: The Political Economy of Security. In Daniel Lambach and Tobias Debiel (Eds.), State Failure Revisited 1: Globalization of Security and Neighborhood Effects. INEF Report 87, Institute for Development and Peace. Retrieved December 9, 2011, from http://inef.uni-due.de/page/documents/Report87.pdf.
Biro, Daniel. [2007]: The (Un) bearable Lightness of…Violence: Warlordism as an Alternate Forms of Governance in the Westphalian Periphery? In Tobias Debiel and Daniel Lambach (Eds.), State Failure Revisited II: Actors of Violence and Alternate Forms of Governance. Institute for Development and Peace, University of Duisburg-Essan, INEF Report. Retrieved, December 9, 2011, from http://inef.uni-due.de/page/documents/Report89.pdf.
Boege, Volker., [January 2007]: Traditional Approaches to Conflict Transformation-Potential and Limits. The Australian Centre for Peace and Conflict Studies, Occasional Paper Series, Number 5. Retrieved May 20, 2010, from http://www.issr.uq.edu.au/acpacs-publications.
Brinkerhoff, Derick W., [2011]: State Fragility and Governance: Conflict Mitigation and Subnational Perspectives. Development Policy Review, 29 (2).
Brooks, Rosa Ehrenreich., [Fall 2005]: Failed States or the State as Failure. In University of Chicago Law Review, 72 (4).
Cahn, Steven M (ed.)., [2005]: Political Philosophy: The Essential Texts. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Carment, David. and Samy, Yiagadeesen., [June 15, 2012]: Assessing State Fragility: A Country Indicators for Foreign Policy Report. CIFP, Carleton University, Ottawa. Retrieved March 12 2013, from www.carleton.ca/cfip.
CIFP., [2007]: Country Ranking Table 2007. Retrieved October 8, 2010, from www.carleton.ca/cifp/app/ffs_ranking.php; and Fragile States Country Report No. 20. Afghanistan Updated for 2009. (2009). Retrieved October 8, 2010, from cifp@carleton.ca.
CIFP., [January 2006]: Failed and Fragile States: A Concept Paper for the Canadian Government. Retrieved September 12, 2010, from http://www.carleton.ca/cifp.
CIFP., [November 2006]: Failed and Fragile States 2006: A Briefing Note for the Canadian Government. Retrieved September 12, 2010, from http://www.carleton.ca/cifp.
Clapham, Christopher., [2002]: The Challenge to the State in a Globalized World. In Development and Change,33 (5).
Conflict Assessment Tool (CAST methodology). [2009]: foreignpolicy.com/…/2009_failed_states_..., retrieved March 16, 2011.
Engels, Frederick., [2004]: The Origin of the Family, Private Property and the State. In Marx/Engels Selected Works, Vol:3. St. Resistance Books, Chipendale, NSW.
Failed and Collapsed States in the International System. [December 2003]: The African Studies Centre, Leiden, The Transnational Institute, Amsterdam, The Center of Social Studies, Coimbra University, and The Peace Research Center- CIP-FUHEM, Madrid. Retrieved December 22, 2007, from http://www.sarai.net/publications/readers/04-crisis-media/04soenke.pdf.
Failed States Index IX2013. [2013]: The Fund for Peace, Retrieved June 16, 2013, from www.failedstatesindex.org.
Fragile States Country Report No. 12. Pakistan October 2007, [2007]: Retrieved October 8 2010, from cifp@carleton.ca. For 2011 index, see Carment and Samy (June 15, 2012).
Fund for Peace. [2009]: fundforpeace.org/web/idex2.php?opti…, retrieved October 8, 2010.
German Development Institute, Briefing Paper. [October 2010]: State Fragility Indices: Potentials, Messages and Limitations. Deutsches Institut fur Entwicklungspolitik.
Gladstone, Jack A., Bates, Robert., David, Epstien., Gurr, Ted R., Lustik, Michael B., Marshall, Monty G., Ulfeder, Jay. and Woodward, Mark. A Global Model for Forecasting Political Instability. [January 2010]: In American Journal of Political Science, 54 (1).
Goldstone, Jack A., Bates, Robert H., Gurr, Ted Robert ., Lustik, Michael., Marshall, Monty G., Ulfeder, Jay. and Woodward, Mark. [September 1-4, 2005]: A Global Forecasting Model of Political Instability. Paper prepared for presentation at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington DC. Retrieved November 5, 2012, from http://globalpolicy.gmu.edu/documents/PITF/PITFglobal.pdf.
Gurr, Ted Robert., Woodward, Mark. and Marshall Monty G. [September 1-4, 2005]: Forecasting Instability: Are Ethnic Wars and Muslim Countries Different? Prepared for delivery at the 2005 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association.
Helman, Gerald B. and Ratner, Steven. [Winter, 1993]: Saving Failed States. In Foreign Policy, 89.
Hewitt, J. Joseph., Wilkenfeld, Jonathan., Gurr, Ted Robert. and Heldt, Birger. [2012]: Peace and Conflict 2012: Executive Summary. Center for International Development and Conflict Management, University of Maryland. Retrieved March 15, 2013, from http://www.cidcm.umd.edu/pc/executive_summary/exec_sum_2012.pdf.
Jackson, Robert H. [Autumn 1987]: Quasi-States, Dual Regimes, and Neoclassical Theory: International Jurisprudence and the Third World. In International Organization, 41 (4).
Jackson, Robert H. and Rosberg, Carl G. [October, 1982]: Why Africa’s Weak States Persist: The Empirical and the Juridical in Statehood. In World Politics, 35 (1).
Lambach, Daniel. [2007]: Close Encounters in the Third Dimension: The Regional Effects of Failure. In Daniel Lambach and Tobias Debiel(Eds.), In State Failure Revisited 1: Globalization of Security and Neighborhood Effects. Institute for Development and Peace INEF Report 87. Retrieved December 9, 2011, from http://inef.uni-due.de/page/documents/Report87.pdf.
Laski, Harold J. [1961]: An Introduction to Politics. London: George Allen & Unwin.
Marshall, Monty G., and Cole, Benjamin R. [2009]: Global Report 2009: Conflict, Governance and State Fragility. Centre for Global Policy, Retrieved May 20, 2013, from http://www.systemicpeace.org/Global%20Report%202009.pdf.
Marshall, Monty G., [2009]: Major Episodes of Political Violence 1946-2009. Retrieved March 17, 2012, from http://www.sytemicpeace.org/warlist.htm.
Marshall, Monty G., [2012]: Polity IV Project: Political Regime Characteristics and Transitions, 1800-2012. Retrieved May 20, 2013, from www.sytemicpeace.org/polity4.htm.
Marshall, Monty G. and Cole Benjamin R., [2011]: Global Report 2011: Conflict, Governance and State Fragility. Centre for Systemic Peace. Retrieved May 20, 2013, http://www.systemicpeace.org/GlobalReport2011.pdf.
Mata, Javier. and Ziaja, Sebastian. [2009]: Users Guide on Measuring Fragility. German Development Institute/ Deutsches Institut fur Entwicklungspolitik and the United Nations Development Programme. Retrieved November 12, 2010, from http://www.die-gdi.de/CMS-Homepage/openwebcms3.nsf/(ynDK_contentByKey)/ ANES-7W89TW/$FILE/UNDP-DIE%202009%20Users%20Guide%20on%20 Measuring%20Fragility.pdf.
Menocal, Alina R., [March 2010]: State Building for Peace: A New Paradigm for International Engagement in Post-Conflict Fragile States? European University Institute, EUI Working Papers. Retrieved, November 5, 2012, from http://ddrn.dk/papers_and_reports-thematic-news-administration-democracy-human-rights-papers-and-reports.html.
Millikin, Jennifer. and Krause, Keith., [2002]: State Failure, State Collapse, and State Reconstruction: Concepts, Lessons and Strategies. In Development and Change,33 (5).
Patrick, Stewart., [2007]: Failed States and Global Security: Empirical Questions and Policy Dilemmas. In International Studies Review, 9.
Plato. [1955]: The Republic, translated with an introduction by H. D. P. Lee. London: Penguin Books.
Raeymaekers, Timothy., [May 2005]: Collapse or Order? Questioning State Collapse in Africa. Conflict Research Group, Working Paper No 1. Retrieved November 8, 2010, from http://ideas.repec.org/p/hic/wpaper/10.html.
Rice, Susan. and Patrick Stewart [2008]: Index of State Weakness 2008. Brookings Global Economy and Development. The Brookings Institution, Washington DC. Retrieved, December 7, 2010, from brookings.edu.
Shearer, I. A., [1994]: Stark’s International Law, 11th ed. Butterworths, London.
State Failure Task Force Report: Phase 3 Findings. [30 September 2000]. Retrieved March 12, 2010, from http://globalpolicy.gmu.edu/ptif/.
State Fragility Index and Matrix 2012. [2012]. Retrieved March 12, 2013, from www.systemicpeace.org.
Stoddard, Abby. [January 2002]: Ethnonationalism and the Failed State: Sources of Civil State Fragmentation in the International Political Economy. In A Graduate Journal of International Affairs, 3.
Retrieved September 24, 2010, from http://www.carleton.ca/emerge/docs_vol3/articles/ethnonationalism/pdf.
The Brookings Index. [2008]. Retrieved, December 7, 2010, from http://www.brookings.edu/~/media/Files/rc/reports/2008/02_weak_states_ index/02_weak_states_index_indicator_scores_pullout.pdf.
The Failed States Index 2013. [2013]: Retrieved June 16, 2013, from ffp.statesindex.org/rankings-2013-sortable.
The Foreign Policy magazine article on FSI 2010. [2010]. Retrieved December 30, 2010, from http://www.foreignpolicy.com/articles/2010/06/21/ the_failed_states_index_2010.
Wallensteen, Peter. [April 7-19, 2000]: Beyond State Failure: On Internal and External Ways of Ending State Failure. Paper presented at the Conference on Failed States, Purdue University, Florence.
Wanlass, Lawrence C., [1956]: Gestell’s History of Political Thought. Surjeet Publications, Delhi.
Weber, Max., [1970]: From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology, Translated, Edited with an Introduction by H. H. Gerth and C. Wright Mills. Routledge & Kegan Paul, London.
Wennmann, Achim. [2010]: Grasping Strengths of Fragile States: Aid Effectiveness Between Top-down and Bottom-up State Building. Centre on Conflict, Development and Peacebuilding, CCDP Working Paper, The Graduate Institute of Geneva. Retrieved November 11, 2011, from http://graduateinstitute.ch/files/live/sites/iheid/files/sites/ccdp/shared/6305/Working%20paper_6_BD.pdf.
Wulf, Herbert. [December 2007]: Challenging the Weberian Concept of the State: The Future of the Monopoly of Violence. Occasional Paper Series Number 9, The American Centre for Peace and conflict Studies. Retrieved December 17, 2011, from http://www.issr.uq.edu.au/acpacs-publications. www.carlton.ca/cfip, retrieved March 12, 2013.
Yannis, Alexandros., [2002]: State Collapse and its implications for Peace-Building and Reconstruction. In Development and Change, 33 (5).
They defined it as a non-self sustaining state, inflicted by civil war, violence, regime instability and economic problems that endangered host population and threatened the neighbours through refugee flows, political tumoil and random warfare. See Helman, Gerald B. and Ratner, Steven. (Winter, 1993). Saving Failed States. Foreign Policy, 89, 3.
Plato (1955). The Republic, translated with an introduction by H. D. P. Lee. Penguin Books, London, p 102.
Aristotle (1962). The Politics, translated with an introduction by T.A. Sinclair. Penguin Books, Middlesex, p 28.
On political organization of the city-states, see Barker, E. (1918). Greek Political Theory: Plato and His Predecessors. Mathuen & Co Ltd., Great Britain, pp. 19-46.
For a discussion on Roman political thought, see Wanlass, L. C. (1956). Gestell’s History of Political Thought. Surjeet Publications, Delhi, pp. 75-80.
For Excerpts from the writings of Hobbes, Locke and Rousseau, see Cahn, S. M. (2005). Political Philosophy: The Essential Texts. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp. 214-320.
See Engels, F. (2004). ‘The Origin of the Family, Private Property and the State’, in Marx/Engels Selected Works, Volume Three. Resistance Books, St. Chipendale, NSW 2004.
Weber, M. (1970). From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology, Translated, Edited with an Introduction by H. H. Gerth and C. Wright Mills. Routledge & Kegan Paul, London, p 78.
Article 1 of the 1930 Montevideo Convention on the Rights and Duties of the State, sets out these four criteria for statehood and most international law definitions follow it. See Shearer, I. A. (1994). Stark’s International Law, 11th ed. Butterworths, London, p 85.
See Jackson, R. H. and Rosberg, C. G. (October 1982). Why Africa’s Weak States Persist: The Empirical and the Juridical in Statehood. In World Politics, 35(1), pp. 1-24; and Jackson, R. H. (Autumn 1987). Quasi-States, Dual Regimes, and Neoclassical Theory: International Jurisprudence and the Third World. In International Organization, 41 (4), pp. 525-30.
Here, if the empirical reality of statehood in non Western societies does not match the Weberian concept of statehood, is it not desirable to define states in non-Western weak settings from an alternate angle of possessing not an absolute monopoly of power over violence but just a reasonable control over violence?
It assesses 52 African countries performance against 58 individual indicators along five categories: security, rule of law, transparency and corruption, participation and Human rights, sustainable economic development and human development. For details see 2013 Ibrahim Index of African Governance: Summary. (2013). Retrieved May 15, 2014, from http://www.moibrahimfoundation.org/downloads/2013/2013-IIAG-summary-report.pdf.
Its data set contains information on 13000 political, economic, social and environmental variables for 162 countries from 1955 onwards. See Goldstone, Jack A., Bates, Robert H., Gurr, Ted Robert., Lustik, Michael., Marshall, Monty G., Ulfeder, Jay., and Woodward, Mark. (September 1-4, 2005). A Global Forecasting Model of Political Instability. Paper prepared for presentation at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington DC. Retrieved November 5, 2012, from http://globalpolicy.gmu.edu/documents/PITF/PITFglobal.pdf.
In Sub-Saharan Africa, all partial democracies failed and among the Muslim countries (with a Muslim population of at least 40 %), both partial and full democracies had a 5 % high incidence of failure than autocratic regimes. See State Failure Task Force Report: Phase 3 Findings. (30 September 2000). Retrieved March 12, 2010, from http://globalpolicy.gmu.edu/ptif/.
Gladstone, J. A., Bates, R., David, E., [et.al.]., A Global Model for Forecasting Political Instability. In American Journal of Political Science, 54 (1), January 2010, pp. 190-208. For Muslim countries, regime type, armed conflict on borders, infant mortality, ethnic or religious minority rule and leader’s years in office were critical in determining the onset of war. See Gurr, Ted Robert., Woodward, Mark. and Marshall Monty G. (September 1-4, 2005). Forecasting Instability: Are Ethnic Wars and Muslim Countries Different? Prepared for delivery at the 2005 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association.
The CSP also manages the Polity IV project which monitors regime changes in 167 countries of the world and provides annual assessments of regime characteristics, changes and data updates. See Marshall, M. G., Polity IV Project: Political Regime Characteristics and Transitions, 1800-2012. Retrieved May 20, 2013, from www.sytemicpeace.org/polity4.htm.
Marshall, M. G., and Cole, B. R., Global Report 2009: Conflict, Governance and State Fragility. Centre for Global Policy, 2009, p 31. Retrieved May 20, 2013, from http://www.systemicpeace.org/Global%20Report%202009.pdf
Marshall, M.G., and Cole, B. R., Global Report 2011: Conflict, Governance and State Fragility. Centre for Systemic Peace, 2011, pp. 36-39. Retrieved May 20, 2013, from http://www.systemicpeace.org/GlobalReport2011.pdf
Afghanistan moved from 4th place in the 2009 index to 3rd place in 2011 and moved up to 2nd place in 2012. Pakistan that stood 27 in 2008 moved down to 29 in 2012 index. See State Fragility Index and Matrix 2012. Retrieved March 12, 2013, from www.systemicpeace.org.
For a list of 315 episodes of armed conflict over 1946-2009, see Marshall, M. G., Major Episodes of political Violence 1946-2009. Retrieved March 17, 2012, from http://www.sytemicpeace.org/warlist.htm.
Retrieved March 12, 2013, from www.cidcm.umd.edu.
Hewitt, J. J., Wilkenfeld, J., Gurr, T. R., and Heldt, B., Peace and Conflict 2012: Executive Summary. Center for International Development and Conflict Management, University of Maryland, Maryland 2012, pp. 5-6. Retrieved March 15, 2013, from http://www.cidcm.umd.edu/pc/executive_summary/exec_sum_2012.pdf.
Authority is defined as the ability to enact binding legislation, exercise effective control over national territory, and provide core public goods. Legitimacy is the capability exercised by a regime to command loyalty and support for its policies and Capacity is the power to mobilize resources towards public ends through competence in political and economic management. See Carment, David. and Samy, Yiagadeesen. (June 15, 2012). Assesing State Fragility: A Country Indicators for Foreign Policy Report. CIFP, Carleton University, Ottawa. Retrieved March 12 2013, from www.carleton.ca/cfip, pp. 3-4.
Retrieved March 12, 2013, from www.carlton.ca/cfip.
Afghanistan’s position remained constant at 2nd in both the 2009 and 2011 Indexes. Pakistan, which was ranked 18 in 2007 index has climbed to no. 9 in the 2011 list. See CIFP Country Ranking Table 2007. Retrieved October 8, 2010, from www.carleton.ca/cifp/app/ffs_ranking.php; and Fragile States Country Report No. 20. Afghanistan Updated for 2009. (2009). Retrieved October 8, 2010, from cifp@carleton.ca; and Fragile States Country Report No. 12. Pakistan October 2007. (2007). Retrieved October 8 2010, from cifp@carleton.ca. For 2011 index, see Carment and Samy (June 15, 2012).
CIFP., Failed and Fragile States 2006: A Briefing Note for the Canadian Government. November 2006. Retrieved September 12, 2010, from http://www.carleton.ca/cifp; and CIFP., Failed and Fragile States: A Concept Paper for the Canadian Government. January 2006. Retrieved September 12, 2010, from http://www.carleton.ca/cifp.
The definition combines institutional, functional approach with liberal and juridical aspects of state failure. See The Foreign Policy magazine article on FSI 2010. (2010). Retrieved December 30, 2010, from http://www.foreignpolicy.com/articles/2010/06/21/ the_failed_states_index_2010.
For indicators, see Failed States Index IX 2013. The Fund for Peace, 2013. Retrieved June 16, 2013, from www.failedstatesindex.org. pp, 9-10. On its Conflict Assessment Tool (CAST methodology), see foreignpolicy.com/…/2009_failed_states_..., retrieved March 16, 2011.
The Failed States Index 2013. Retrieved June 16, 2013, from ffp.statesindex.org/rankings-2013-sortable.
The Failed States Index 2013, pp. 15-20. Afghanistan Country Report with indicator scores for 2010 can be accessed at fundforpeace.org/web/idex2.php?opti…, retrieved October 8, 2010.
The Brookings Index has not provided new rankings of state weakness in the developing world since 2008.
Susan Rice and Patrick Stewart. (2008). Index of State Weakness 2008. Brookings Global Economy and development.Washington DC.: The Brookings Institution, 3, Retrieved December 7, 2010, from brookings.edu.
Data on 20 individual indicators for each of the 141 states is available at http://www.brookings.edu/~/media/Files/rc/reports/2008/02_weak_states_ index/02_weak_states_index_indicator_scores_pullout.pdf, Retrieved December 7, 2010.
Pakistan is in the 2nd quintile or weak states (overall 33 and 5th in the 2nd quintile). See Rice and Stewart. (2008).
This is because some scholars share positions both in PITF and that of the CIDCM and are instrumental in developing the data set for both the indices.
As Wallensteen argues, state failure can take place without a civil war and there can be a civil war without state failure. See Wallensteen, P., Beyond State Failure: On Internal and External Ways of Ending State Failure. Paper presented at the Conference on Failed States, Purdue University, Florence April 7-19, 2000.
Wulf calls the concept of monopoly over violence as ‘Eurocentric and myopic.’ See Wulf, Herbert. (December 2007). Challenging the Weberian Concept of the State: The Future of the Monopoly of Violence. Occasional Paper Series Number 9, The American Centre for Peace and conflict Studies. Retrieved December 17, 2011, from http://www.issr.uq.edu.au/acpacs-publications, p. 6.
See Ibid. Axtman, terms this process ‘denationalization of the state’ or ‘destatization’ of the political system, where the state either entirely transfers public responsibilities or exercises these in partnership with para-statal, NGOs. See Axtmann, Roland. (July 2004). The State of the State: The Model of the Modern State and its Contemporary Transformation. International Political Science Review, 25 (3), 268-71.
See Biro, Daniel. (2007). The (Un) bearable Lightness of…Violence: Warlordism as an Alternate Forms of Governance in the Westphalian Periphery? In Tobias Debiel and Daniel Lambach (Eds.), State Failure Revisited II: Actors of Violence and Alternate Forms of Governance. Institute for Development and Peace, University of Duisburg-Essan, INEF Report. Retrieved, December 9, 2011, from http://inef.uni-due.de/page/documents/Report89.pdf, p. 89; and Wulf. (December 2007), p.6.
For globalization’s adverse impacts on state’s stability, see Clapham, Christopher. (2002). The Challenge to the State in a Globalized World. Development and Change,33 (5), p. 786; Failed and Collapsed States in the International System. (December 2003). The African Studies Centre, Leiden, The Transnational Institute, Amsterdam, The Center of Social Studies, Coimbra University, and The Peace Research Center- CIP-FUHEM, Madrid. Retrieved December 22, 2007, from http://www.sarai.net/publications/readers/04-crisis-media/04soenke.pdf; Bilgin, Pinar. and Morton, Adam David. (2007). Rethinking State Failure: The Political Economy of Security. In Daniel Lambach and Tobias Debiel (Eds.), State Failure Revisited 1: Globalization of Security and Neighborhood Effects. INEF Report 87, Institute for Development and Peace. Retrieved December 9, 2011, from http://inef.uni-due.de/page/documents/Report87.pdf; Stoddard, Abby. (January 2002). Ethnonationalism and the Failed State: Sources of Civil State Fragmentation in the International Political Economy. A Graduate Journal of International Affairs, no. 3. Retrieved September 24, 2010, from http://www.carleton.ca/emerge/docs_vol3/articles/ethnonationalism/pdf, pp. 3-6; and Yannis, Alexandros. (2002). State Collapse and its implications for Peace-Building and Reconstruction, Development and change, 33 (5), pp. 817-835.
Brooks, terms the category of failed states as largely deceptive and emphasizes that Afghanistan, Sierra Leone, Congo or Somalia were never functioning modern states because from the very beginning these exercised little monopoly of violence over their territories including their border areas. See Brooks, Rosa Ehrenreich. (Fall 2005). Failed States or the State as Failure. University of Chicago Law Review, 72 (4), p.15.
They argue that such success is possible only if the idea of the state is taken completely out of its historical context and regarded as an institutional form that owes little or nothing to the historical forces that created it. See Millikin, Jennifer. and Krause, Keith. (2002). State Failure, State Collapse, and State Reconstruction: Concepts, Lessons and Strategies. Development and Change,33 (5), p. 762.
See Bilgin, Pinar. and Morton, Adam David. (2002). Historicising Representations of Failed States: Beyond the Cold-War Annexation of the Social Sciences? Third World Quarterly, 23 (1), pp. 55-67.
These include ignoring good governance requirements in resource rich countries, providing financial havens for ill gotten wealth of the Third World elites, sustaining demands for narcotics, timber, diamonds and engaging in armaments trade in conflict zones of the world. See Patrick, Stewart. (2007). Failed States and Global Security: Empirical Questions and Policy Dilemmas. International Studies Review, 9, pp. 644-62.
Lambach, D., Close Encounters in the Third Dimension: The Regional Effects of Failure. In Daniel Lambach and Tobias Debiel(Eds.), State Failure Revisited 1: Globalization of Security and Neighborhood Effects. Institute for Development and Peace INEF Report 87. 2007. Retrieved December 9, 2011, from http://inef.uni-due.de/page/documents/Report87.pdf, pp. 35-37.
As Boege insists that absence of state order should not be confused with absence of any kind of order, rather it is better to see failed states as hybrid orders, where ‘pre-modern, modern and post modern elements mix and overlap’. See Boege, Volker. (January 2007). Traditional Approaches to Conflict Transformation-Potential and Limits. The Australian Centre for Peace and Conflict Studies, Occasional Paper Series, Number 5. Retrieved May 20, 2010, from http://www.issr.uq.edu.au/acpacs-publications, pp. 15-20.
Raeymaekers, Timothy. (May 2005). Collapse or Order? Questioning State Collapse in Africa. Conflict Research Group, Working Paper No 1. Retrieved November 8, 2010, from http://ideas.repec.org/p/hic/wpaper/10.html, pp, 6-7. Anderson recognizes the important role of religious groups in service provision in fragile settings. See Anderson, Lisa. (Fall 2004). Antiquated Before They Can Ossify: States that Fail Before They Form. Journal of International Affairs,58 (1), pp. 13-14.
See Menocal, Alina R. (March 2010). State Building for Peace: A New Paradigm for International Engagement in Post-Conflict Fragile States? European University Institute, EUI Working Papers. Retrieved, November 5, 2012, from http://ddrn.dk/papers_and_reports-thematic-news-administration-democracy-human-rights-papers-and-reports.html, p. 15.
See Mata, Javier. and Ziaja, Sebastian. (2009). Users Guide on Measuring Fragility. German Development Institute/ Deutsches Institut fur Entwicklungspolitik and the United Nations Development Programme. Retrieved November 12, 2010, from http://www.die-gdi.de/CMS-Homepage/openwebcms3.nsf/(ynDK_contentByKey)/ ANES-7W89TW/$FILE/UNDP-DIE%202009%20Users%20Guide%20on%20 Measuring%20Fragility.pdf; and German Development Institute, Briefing Paper. (October 2010). State Fragility Indices: Potentials, Messages and Limitations. Deutsches Institut fur Entwicklungspolitik.
Brinkerhoff, Derick W. (2011). State Fragility and Governance: Conflict Mitigation and Sub-national Perspectives. Development Policy Review, 29 (2), p. 134.
It is for this reason that Wennmann, criticizes these indices for using data on past events and conditions, which fail to provide the dynamics of fragility in either the current passing year or the coming future ones and their failure to identify processes and actors involved in making states fragile. See Wennmann, Achim. (2010). Grasping Strengths of Fragile States: Aid Effectiveness Between Top-down and Bottom-up State Building. Centre on Conflict, Development and Peacebuilding, CCDP Working Paper, The Graduate Institute of Geneva. Retrieved November 11, 2011, from http://graduateinstitute.ch/files/live/sites/iheid/files/sites/ccdp/shared/6305/Working%20paper_6_BD.pdf, p. 20.